



|
Free Riders
Suppose that an area has a terrible mosquito problem. An
enterprising young man decides that it would be fairly cheap
to spray the area ponds and swamps to control mosquitoes.
(In most species of mosquitoes, the larval stage is spent
living in water, but breathing air.) He also reasons that
most of the people would value a reduction in mosquitoes a
great deal. However, even if his assessment of the situation
is correct, an attempt to form a business will run into a
serious problem, the problem of the free rider.
To see the problem of the free rider, consider the
options open to a "customer" of the mosquito-reduction
service who is asked to pay $25.00. If he pays $25.00, he
will get a reduction in mosquitoes (if enough other people
also pay to make the service financially viable). If he
refuses to pay, he will still get the same reduction in
mosquitoes (again assuming that there are enough other
people who pay so the service is financially viable). Once
the service is produced, it cannot be withheld from people
who do not pay for it. Mosquitoes attempt to bite the first
target they find, and are not likely to bite only those who
do not pay businessmen who are trying to kill them. Given
the options, each person is likely to reason that his $25.00
is unimportant relative to the total amount needed to make
the enterprise successful, and thus the results will not
depend on his contribution. However, if everyone thinks this
way, the enterprise cannot come into being. Hence there is a
paradox: though people may want the service a great deal,
and though it may be cheap to produce, it may be
unprofitable to produce.
The mosquito control program is an example of a public
good. Public goods have two characteristics: they are
nonexcludable, which means that it is not possible to
exclude those who do not pay for the good or service, and
they are nonrival, which means that one person's use
of the good or service does not diminish the amount
available to others. In addition to mosquito control, the
problem extends to police protection and national defense,
lighthouses, the development of knowledge, and
television.
There are a variety of ways to cope with the free rider
problem. Sometimes there are alternative ways to provide a
service that makes exclusion possible: window screens are a
substitute, though hardly a perfect one, for spraying
mosquitoes; and cable and pay TV are substitutes for
broadcast TV. Both radio and television broadcasts are
public goods. In the early days of radio, giving away the
broadcast was seen as a way to sell radio sets, but soon an
entrepreneur discovered that although one could not sell the
programming to the audience, one could sell the audience to
advertisers, and this sale of the audience is the basis for
network television.
Another way to overcome free rider problems is through
social pressure. Community leaders recognize a problem and
organize to solve it. Those who do not cooperate can be
ostracized or in some way their relations with the rest of
the community can be adversely affected. If some of those
bothered by mosquitoes in the previous example mutually
agree to form an association to solve the problem, those who
do not voluntarily contribute may find life as an outcast
unpleasant. The $25.00 is contributed not to buy mosquito
control, but to buy social acceptance. The way a voluntary
group can solve the free rider problem is by changing what
the payment buys.
An alternative to the social pressures of voluntary
groups is the coercion of the government. The government
could provide a mosquito-control program, paying for it by
taxing citizens. Even when voluntary organization is
possible, it may be much easier (and require fewer resources
to collect the money necessary for the program) to use the
power of the government to provide public goods. In
addition, governments usually will not allow private groups to
provide services that have force as part of the product,
such as police protection, the court system, or national
defense, because the private groups would then have the
potential to expand and threaten the government itself.
You might notice that the logic involved in the free
rider problem is the same as in the problem
of the commons and the prisoners'
dilemma. In fact the free rider problem can be seen as
an extension of the prisoners' dilemma from a two-person
game to a multi-person game. The best solution as far as the
group is concerned involves cooperative behavior. However,
each individual can be made better off if he and he alone
can cheat on the cooperation. Because everyone has this
incentive, there is a strong tendency for cooperation to
break down unless added incentives (such as force or social
ostracism) are introduced into the payoffs.
The free rider phenomenon is not always a bad thing. For
example, it is the free rider phenomenon that keeps large
numbers of sellers from colluding and charging higher prices
to consumers. In this case, it prevents the formation of
subgroups from working against the interests of the whole
group.
When discussing efficiency, we considered the case in
which a bundle of resources had three possible uses, one
valued at $25, one at $22, and one at $20. We concluded that
for a market to be efficient, it had to send those resources
to the place where they were worth $25. Suppose, though,
that this $25-use is a public good, so the seller will not
be able to collect the value that people get from the
product. Will the resources go to the most valuable use or
will we have an inefficient use of resources?
We now turn from free riders to "free" resources.
  
Copyright
Robert Schenk
|